16 May 2013
The Motor Industry, Industrial Policy and SA's Trade Deficit
But focus on the trade deficit asks not about the underlying competitiveness problem but rather what would happen to sectoral imports and exports if government support were reduced. This looks at the trade deficit as a sectoral issue rather than a broader macroeconomic phenomenon.
One of my early reports on MIDP illustrates the risk of this approach by showing that replacing imports or increasing exports through subsidized domestic production is a very costly way to earn foreign exchange.
I estimated that in 2005 vehicle exports were being subsidized at a rate of about 30 percent of domestic value added and production for domestic sale at a rate of at least 60 percent. At these rates, each R100,000 of vehicle exports was costing South Africa R130,000 of domestic resources. That is, earning $100 of foreign exchange through vehicle exports was costing South Africa $130. Similarly each $100 of foreign exchange saved through sourcing vehicles domestically rather than through imports was costing at least $160.
Reducing the trade deficit through subsidies to a non-competitive motor industry is very costly indeed.
Is the APDP any better? I have estimated that in the final year of MIDP vehicle exports were being subsidized at a rate of 17.3 percent of local value added and production of vehicles for domestic sale at a rate of 62.5 percent. By my estimates the APDP has increased the export subsidy to 27.7 percent and the import substitution subsidy to 71.7 percent. At these increased rates we might hope to see some reduction in the motor industry trade deficit. But the cost will be even higher than it has been in the past.
What does the dti make of this? Viewing everything from the perspective of its industry clients, it looks at the trade deficit and most other longer term development problems as sectoral issues. Rather than examining and dealing with underlying structural and regulatory barriers to development, it asks its industry clients how large and what type of subsidy they require to overcome the problems of investing and producing in South Africa.
At my last count, the government was giving subsidies of well over R10 billion per year to a few auto firms, and imposing a cost on consumers of close to R20 billion per year. Over its first decade MIDP subsidies came close to R100 billion. The government continues to "negotiate" with the big auto firms about improving their competitiveness. The dance goes on and the subsidies continue. We will certainly see new forms of support. This has not produced a competitive industry and it has not solved any real or imagined trade deficit problems.
Unfortunately the motor industry is not an isolated case. The textile and garment industry receives large subsidies, mostly paid for by consumers, even as much of it disappears or migrates to Swaziland and Lesotho. The dti has recently revived a failed policy from decades ago by releasing a list of 10 "special economic zones," defined by product and province, that it wishes to support.
The lesson for investors is that success in South Africa is enjoyed by cozy monopolies and those with access to generous government support in the form of subsidies and barriers to competition. This is good for some investors, but not for South African development. Longer term growth depends on the creation of an environment in which investors can and do compete, domestically and internationally.
02 May 2013
The Malaysian Model and its Relevance for South Africa
Like South Africa, Malaysia has been ruled since independence by a single coalition dominated by the interests of the majority ethnic group. An election this Sunday will provide a real possibility of political change. The occasion calls for a realistic assessment of what has come to be regarded as the "Malaysian model."
My own view is that a) the divergence of Malaysia's macroeconomic policies from conventional "best practice" has been greatly overstated, b) whatever the merits of "bumiputra" affirmative action policies, the costs have also been large and by now certainly outweigh the benefits, and c) key features of targeted industrial policies have impeded rather than promoted the country's economic growth.
These views are echoed concisely in a Financial Times opinion piece. According to the columnist, David Pilling, failures of past policies make political change a real possibility.
"There is huge anger at entrenched corruption and buddy-buddy crony capitalism. Many Malaysians have come to the conclusion, almost certainly correct, that affirmative action has outlived its purpose and is holding the country back.
"There is increasing recognition, too, that economic performance is not all it might have been....Manufacturing exports have been stalled for years and attempts to build an indigenous steel and car industry have flopped. It has been easier for cosseted businessmen to jostle for lucrative state contracts than to compete internationally."
Pilling's view is that there is a "need to roll back a system based on race and patronage in favour of one based on competition and merit."
Whether political change happens, and whether it will result in meaningful policy reform remain to be seen. But discussions in South Africa and elsewhere need to be informed by a realistic view of the nature and impacts of the "Malaysian model." Otherwise the dti and others will continue to copy Malaysia's failures rather than learning the real reasons behind its successes.
09 April 2013
SA's Motor Industry—Once Again
The implicit answer, supported by a number of online reader comments, is that the industry is not internationally competitive. This is consistent with my own analysis over the years—the ability of MIDP and other government policies to attract investment and promote exports reflects, not the industry's competitiveness, but rather the value of government incentives.
The MIDP was recently replaced by the APDP. This tweaked some of the details of public support for the industry—production subsidies are now given to domestic sales as well as exports; the dti can now hand out cash investment incentives on a more discretionary basis. But the magnitude of public support has not diminished; and it is determined largely in consultation with the major firms who tell the government how much support they require to overcome the high costs of investing and producing in SA. In other words, the type and magnitude of public support depend on how uncompetitive these firms are in SA.
The danger now is that the dti will seek to solve this sectoral trade deficit "problem" in ways that will increase the burdens on consumers and taxpayers, and further diminish SA's manufacturing competitiveness. A simple "solution," for instance, would be to impose local content requirements on the industry and restrict imports through higher tariffs or other measures—in other words, return SA to the bizarre and highly costly policies of the Apartheid era.
The government could, and almost certainly will, employ more subtle subsidies and incentives to serve its motor industry clients. A tender document just released by the DPE, for instance, solicits advice on how Transnet and Eskom can be used to increase motor industry profitability. Reducing Transnet and Eskom costs would certainly be good for the entire economy. But to give special privileges to the motor industry (which already benefits from special Transnet pricing deals on its exports) would perpetuate the failures of the current policies that seek to improve competitiveness by subsidizing uncompetitive firms and industries.
25 March 2013
Subsidies, Bailouts and Markets
Of course, it is not just state companies and agencies that benefit from public subsidies. Direct government support and regulation are viewed by some as necessary for South African industrial development. The consequences of this approach can be similar to the effects of bailouts of state enterprises.
In this regard, Mr. Louw's remarks reminded me of a brilliant commentary by another FMF member, on the impacts of industrial policy in South Africa's motor industry. In a prize-winning letter to Business Day in 2005 Jim Harris explained how the MIDP (Motor Industry Development Program, recently rechristened as APDP) supports a few companies, but punishes consumers and retards the country's long-term economic development. His remarks were controversial and attracted fierce reactions from some fellow FMF members—at least those associated with the motor industry.
Mr. Harris' letter signalled the start of a vigorous public debate about MIDP that, if nothing else, clarified the nature and magnitude of the subsidies enjoyed by the industry. As with the bailouts of SAA, the MIDP and related subsidies protect a few heavily dependent companies at the expense of consumers, jobs and the poor.
I have been unable to find any follow-up on the FMF website to Jim Harris' early foray into South Africa's most important industrial policy. It would be useful for the FMF to complement the comments on bailouts to state enterprises (and on the US bailout of General Motors) with a discussion of the massive and continuing subsidies to firms in the South African motor industry and other selected sectors.
25 November 2010
Challenges to SADC Regional and Global Integration
I was asked recently to give an assessment of progress and possible future directions for economic integration in the Southern Africa Development Community (SADC). The resulting paper and presentation summarize my views on some of the main challenges facing the region.
The Importance of SADC Integration
Trade policy is one of many tools for improving productivity, increasing competitiveness and promoting long-term economic development. It is about far more than tariff negotiations. Similarly, SADC is about much more than implementing and extending the Trade Protocol. Great progress has been made; but much more could be done to achieve more meaningful and productive economic integration—globally and in the region. Despite substantial reform trade in SADC remains costly (see Table 2 of my paper) and continues to be hampered by well-intended initiatives whose unintended negative consequences for the region’s development are insufficiently appreciated.
SADC is economically small; for most internationally traded goods regional markets are too small and fragmented to provide a base for globally competitive operations. To focus primarily on products in which firms rely on protection to compete locally and regionally is of limited value and often harmful. The focus must be on creating an environment in which investors can think about competing internationally. When this happens, SADC growth will accelerate and the SADC market will eventually merit real attention. But growth based on global markets must be the primary concern.
SADC is also geographically large, and the resulting hard and soft logistical infrastructure challenges are among the main constraints to effective global integration of the region.
A SADC Customs Union?
Early plans called for formation of a SADC customs union by 2010. This deadline will not be met. A SADC customs union could reduce the need for intra-regional border controls, especially those related to enforcing rules of origin. Against this, however, must be weighed several considerations.
1. Rules of origin are not the only barriers to regional integration in SADC. Dealing with the other barriers is of great economic importance; and many of them can be dealt with independently of a customs union.
2. Based on experience to date, a number of countries are simply not ready for a customs union, or even for complete intra-SADC free trade. A customs union in which members insist on restricting intra-regional trade for economic development purposes would be futile, as would a union in which poorer countries are too dependent on customs revenue to contemplate reducing import duty rates. There are even more basic issues such as rules and guarantees on transit trade that can and should be dealt with long before a customs union or even completion of the SADC FTA.
3. A customs union requires agreement on overall tariff policy—not only on common external tariffs but also on future preferential and MFN-based tariff negotiations as well as antidumping, safeguards and other contingent protection. Member States are far from united on these questions. Mauritius plans to eliminate all MFN import duties and become a duty-free island. South Africa, on the other hand, sees import tariffs as a key tool of industrial policy. Agreement on a common tariff would require either undoing substantial reforms that have already taken place in some countries, or forcing others to move more swiftly on MFN tariff reform than they are prepared to do.
4. Differences in approach to trade and economic development policy might make it difficult and maybe even inadvisable to move too quickly towards a SADC customs union. Allowing for different approaches permits countries to experiment and to learn by themselves and from other SADC partners. A “lowest common denominator” approach, which might result from moving in unison towards a customs union now, could hold back more progressive and ambitious countries. Countries like Mauritius can “raise the bar” for all SADC Member States in setting targets for tariff, trade and industrial policies.
Is SACU a Model?
As the oldest customs union in the world, and one that includes five SADC Member States, the Southern Africa Customs Union (SACU) might be thought of as a model for a SADC customs union. However,
1. In some respects SACU is a customs union more in name than in fact. Use of the infant industry protection clause, for instance, has resulted in significant intra-SACU trade barriers aimed at achieving industrial policy goals of questionable value. All intra-SACU imports are subject to complete customs control by each country, with intra-SACU trade being subject to inspection and documentation on each side of all borders.
2. The current SACU Agreement calls for joint decision-making on all MFN tariff decisions. Until now no SACU wide tariff body has been set up, and South Africa continues as de facto arbiter on tariff policy. The Economic Partnership Agreement (EPA) negotiations with the EU revealed potentially serious differences among SACU members.
3. The SACU revenue sharing formula is viewed by poorer SADC Member States as a potential model for a SADC. This is primarily because it allocates a disproportionate share of customs revenues to the four smallest members. This is not replicable on a SADC-wide basis, nor should it even be thought of as a possible model.
There certainly are lessons to be learned from SACU. But it is unlikely to be an appropriate starting point or model for a SADC customs union, at least in its present form.
Monitoring SADC Performance
The approach to monitoring progress in SADC so far has been largely “legalistic”—focusing on intra-SADC trade and the extent to which countries are meeting agreed liberalization commitments. This is important. But it is also critical not to lose sight of the broader purpose of SADC integration—it is part of a much larger project to improve productivity and competitiveness of SADC Member States so that they can integrate more effectively into the global economy.
Why not complement existing monitoring efforts with a new and possibly much less “coercive” attempt to monitor progress in improving international competitiveness? Benchmarking success stories and identifying ways in which they can be extended and generalized could be very useful to all Member States.
At the risk of oversimplification, SADC appears to operate now at two different levels. At one level it is dominated by high level political visionaries guided by dreams of and plans for developing a greater southern Africa and ultimately a more unified and successful African continent. On a day-to-day basis, however, it is dominated by trade negotiators, who see “concessions” on the use of tariffs, non-tariff barriers (NTBs) and other economic instruments as a surrender of sovereignty. They tend to view their main goal as to achieve openings in external markets. They do not see trade liberalization as part of a strategy to promote economic development by improving global competitiveness.
This is not uncommon. Trade negotiations are often driven by a mercantilist fiction, that imports are an evil to be avoided and that trade is a zero sum game.
In fact most of what trade negotiators deal in are issues that can best be resolved through domestic, unilateral trade policy reform. Most of what is needed to improve any country’s business environment and international competitiveness can be done at home. It does not have to be “negotiated” with other countries.
Of course, pursuing domestic reform through international negotiations can help overcome domestic resistance by using the fiction that reform is part of the price to pay for obtaining similar “concessions” by foreign partners. However, negotiators need to see through this fiction and recognize domestic reform as a means of enhancing development through improved competitiveness.
Unfortunately, negotiators more often see themselves as representatives of domestic interests that might be negatively affected by trade reform; they see their main “stakeholders” as existing investors and producers that benefit from current trade restrictions, and not those that compete in world markets or future investors, producers, workers and consumers that will benefit from improvements in the business environment arising from trade reform.
This might be changed by some broadening of the focus of SADC itself—working together not so much to promote trade reform and trade negotiations as goals in themselves, but rather to identify and deal with the real constraints to growth. This does not necessarily require all Members to move at the same pace. Countries that wish to fast track certain reforms can do so, and in the process provide valuable information and maybe even a model to partner countries. Some issues will be more important and/or more amenable to change in some countries than in others.
This is not to denigrate past accomplishments or ongoing initiatives. It is to suggest, rather, the value of complementing past successes with a greater emphasis on monitoring and improving competitiveness in the region. A first step might be to complement annual trade audits and ongoing NTB monitoring with annual competitiveness audits. The purpose would not be to “name and shame” individual countries or to enforce negotiated agreements, but rather to highlight lessons that can be utilized by any Member and to identify areas and mechanisms for independent action and regional cooperation for the mutual benefit of the citizens of all Member States.
20 May 2010
Follow the Money
This strays a bit from my usual range of economics issues. But it certainly is about following the money.
Thailand's fugitive former PM Thaksin recently hired a Canadian lawyer, Robert Amsterdam, who flew over to Bangkok last week to visit the red-shirt leaders. CNN obliged by giving him an incredibly soft interview and international sound bite on his client's behalf. Much better was an interview he did with an Al-Jazeera reporter from Kuala Lumpur. She asked some good questions and he sidestepped almost all of them.
Amsterdam seems to have quite an international reputation. He has been written up in recent articles in a Bucharest magazine and Belgrade newspaper of all places.
Canada's Globe and Mail also did an interview with him last week. See the article and some interesting comments.
11 December 2009
Making a Mockery of Competitiveness
One of the few genuine innovations in South Africa's APDP, the motor industry support program that will replace the MIDP, is a requirement of a minimum scale of operations in order to qualify for the program's very generous financial benefits. Although the details of the program still have not been gazetted, we understand that in order to qualify vehicle assemblers will have to produce a minimum of 50,000 vehicles per year. The idea is to encourage international competitiveness by achieving some economies of scale in production.
The scheme does raise some questions.
1. Why is it necessary for the government to instruct global auto firms on efficient scales of production? (It is not; but under MIDP and APDP it is not necessary to be competitive in order to make big profits by producing in South Africa.)
2. Will production of 50,000 vehicles per year provide sufficient scale to compete with true international major league plants? (Generally not; competitive plants elsewhere produce at least 100,000 per year.)
3. And of course one might wonder how firms will try to get around the new requirement in order to continue to take advantage of the large subsidies made available by the government (and paid for through the "generosity" of South African vehicle consumers and taxpayers) without ramping up production.
But at least the new requirement appears to be a feint in the direction of encouraging some competitiveness on the part of the local industry.
An announcement by the government-operated East London Industrial Development Zone (ELIDZ) provides an answer to the third question. ELIDZ has told the press that it will soon announce the signing of several tenants in a new "multi-OEM assembly plant" it will build in the zone. What is the purpose of such a plant? To enable companies sharing the facility to produce at volumes of 10,000 vehicles per year, or even as low as just a few thousand and still qualify for the APDP benefits that are contingent on meeting the 50,000 per year volume target. It apparently will "work" as long as the total of all vehicles produced by all tenants reaches 50,000 per year.
How will this encourage increased competitiveness, the stated goal of the new policy? It will not. In fact it will simply replicate the highly inefficient pattern of small scale production of multiple models and other automotive products under one roof that was encouraged by protection in pre-MIDP days and by continued protection and MIDP benefits since then.
26 November 2009
Another Industrial Policy "Success" Story
Volkswagen South Africa (VWSA) has won a contract worth about R30 billion to export South African-made VW Polos over the next 6 years. The company's Managing Director, David Powels, says that 685 new jobs will created. This will be viewed in many quarters as an early success of the latest incarnation of South African government support for the motor industry (APDP, formerly known as MIDP).
Powels has been reported separately as saying that producing cars in SA is up to 40 percent more costly than in competitor locations in Asia and Europe. If that is the case, how did VWSA win this contract? The answer -- subsidies under MIDP, APDP and other government programs are expected to compensate for this cost differential.
Suppose that the cars to be exported under the contract are only 35 percent more costly to produce than in the next best location. If this is so, VWSA must be counting on government subsidies of at least R10.5 billion (35 percent of R30 billion, the value of the contract). Otherwise it would make no sense for VW to source the vehicles in South Africa.
What is the size of the subsidy per job? Based on the VWSA estimate of 685 new jobs, the expected subsidy is R15.3 million per job over the 6 years of the contract, or R2.55 million per job per year. This is 25 times higher than the average annual wage in manufacturing in South Africa (about R100,000). Quite a success!!
13 October 2009
More Protection for the SA Clothing Industry?
This follows another recent recommendation and government agreement to reduce the duties on a wide range of imported fabrics from 22 percent to zero.
ITAC argues that these measures will “provide significant encouragement and support to the industry while its extensive efforts to restructure to become more competitive are continuing;” and they will have little inflationary impact.
ITAC does not show its estimates of the amount of support this will provide. My own calculations show that before any of the recent recommendations, i.e. with tariff rates of 40 percent on clothing and 22 percent on most fabrics, SA garment producers were being subsidized at a rate of about 94 percent of value added. In non-technical terms, this means that the tariff structure allowed them to produce garments at a cost 94 percent higher than foreign competitors and still compete in the local market. This is a very high level of support, higher than in just about any other industry in South Africa.
Under the proposed new measures, the subsidy will increase to 114 percent for garment producers that are still subject to the 22 percent fabric tariff. And for those that are able to take advantage of the new rebate that lowers the fabric tariff to zero, the subsidy will be 180 percent. They will be able to produce at almost three times the cost of foreign competitors and still be able to “compete” in the domestic market.
Does this encourage restructuring and increased competitiveness? No, it subsidizes high cost producers, and enables them to survive despite much higher costs than international competitors, with no need to adjust or to improve their competitiveness.
On top of this, the government is mulling even further subsidies to the industry. No details have been made available, but under proposals that have been mentioned publicly I estimate that the rate of subsidy could be over 300 percent.
It is difficult to imagine how firms that require this kind of support could be transformed into internationally competitive producers.
What, then, is the real goal of government support? It seems to be to protect vulnerable and/or a privileged subset of the country’s workers. But is subsidizing continued production and further investments in training and equipment to sustain existing jobs in non-competitive firms or industries the best way to do this? The cost is high. Clothing and footwear account for 5 percent of consumer expenditures in South Africa. For lower income households the percentage is much higher. A 40 or 45 percent tax on such a basic consumer good is a cruel and regressive tax indeed. While an increase in the tariff might provide further short-term relief for garment workers, it will be at the much greater expense of all workers and consumers in the country, and especially the poor.
A government official recently told me that one of the main problems with the SA garment industry is that the equipment is very old. The unwillingness of firms to invest in upgrading this equipment, despite current high levels of protection, would be a rational response to their view that much of the industry will never be able to compete.
I asked about the age of workers in these factories. The answer: “about the same as the equipment.” This might also reflect a rational response by young workers who see no future in this industry. It also reduces the costs of any necessary adjustment if industrial support is gradually withdrawn. An increase in support might not only impose higher immediate costs on taxpayers and consumers, but might draw new workers into the industry and increase future adjustment costs.
What is the bottom line? The government needs to move out of the box that views subsidies to non-competitive producers and industries as the best way to help the country’s workers, taxpayers and consumers. Let's deal directly with what is essentially a social welfare problem – assisting workers in declining firms – and free the government to think more creatively about an industrial strategy that points to the future rather than the past.
Health for Empowerment and Growth
These countries should take note of some new research findings from the US. A recent report by Chay, Guryan and Mazumder shows the startling and large effects of improvements in basic health care for black infants in the 1960s arising from hospital integration. They show that better infant health care explains substantial improvements in educational achievement, independently of other causes such as school integration and changes in family backgrounds.
The lesson for countries like Malaysia and South Africa is clear. If you want to promote empowerment of disadvantaged groups, use basic health and education to tackle the root causes of inequality and the real barriers to economic opportunity. The resulting improvements in human capabilities will pay additional dividends in the form of higher long-term productivity growth as well.
19 November 2008
A "New" Program of Auto Industry Support
17 July 2007
Unsafe at any Speed: MIDP and SACU
The articles cleverly explore the links between SACU's new revenue sharing formula, South Africa's Motor Industry Development Program (MIDP) and the recent boom in car sales in South Africa, to illustrate how the new formula turns all previous interests in SACU trade policy on their heads. By fattening the government budgets of the four small and less developed SACU members (Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia and Swaziland—the "BLNS countries" in SACU-speak) the formula has turned these countries into avid supporters of a program designed to subsidize South African motor industry producers at the expense of South African and BLNS consumers. The cost of the program to BLNS consumers is now dwarfed by the (far more than) offsetting revenue transfers to BLNS governments (to the tune of 23 percent of GDP in the case of Lesotho and 12 percent in Swaziland). And now poor South African consumers/taxpayers are saddled not only with high priced motor vehicles but also with the burden of huge fiscal transfers to the BLNS.
South Africa's National Treasury, quite naturally, is bemoaning not only the size of the revenue transfers, but also the difficulties they will create in reaching agreement on badly needed rationalization of the SACU tariff structure. Under the new SACU arrangement, tariff rate decisions are meant to be decided collectively by all members. Having been turned into the greatest supporters of South Africa's protectionist trade policies, the BLNS countries are unlikely to favour tariff reductions that threaten their fiscal windfalls. Before complaining too much, however, South Africa should look at its own central role in promoting agreement on this new revenue formula.
Among the cutest parts of the M&G articles is an illustrative calculation of the amount of revenues transferred to the BLNS whenever a South African buys a new imported car. Based on an import duty rate of 25 percent and an assumed transfer of about half of these revenues to the BLNS, the article shows that the purchaser of a new "Volvaru" that cost a dealer R200 000 would pay just over R25 000 to the BLNS, of which about R5 000 would go to the government of Swaziland and R4 100 to Lesotho.
In fact the numbers are much worse than that. The import duty on cars is now 30 percent, not 25 percent. And, according to our estimates of last year, the share of duty collections going to the BLNS is about 88 percent, not 50 percent. This means that a South African buyer of the above-mentioned "Volvaru" would contribute about R52 000 to the BLNS, of which over R11 000 would go to Swaziland and R7 400 to Lesotho (and greater amounts to the governments of Botswana and Namibia).
This tale leaves South African consumers and taxpayers with much to ponder. The consequences of the MIDP and of the new SACU arrangement are surely much different than whatever might have been expected by those who designed them; and their combined impact is far worse than either of them individually. Two bad policies do not make a good one.
09 May 2007
South Africa's MIDP
However, an industry representative was reported yesterday as saying that government support of the industry is "below par" relative to other countries and will have to be improved in order to make the industry competitive.
How much support has the MIDP given the industry? Answers to this basic question are difficult to obtain. I have estimated that typical subsidies to motor vehicle and/or components manufacturers range from 260 to over 650 percent of the size of MIDP-supported investments.
Support to the motor industry from export subsidies and import duties has almost certainly exceeded R100 billion over the life of the program so far. The cost to consumers has been similar. How can an industry that relies on such levels of support expect to become "competitive"? Surely the solution is not to give even more subsidies.
Australia, after whose program the MIDP was initially modelled, is entering the final phase of its "Automotive Competitivness and Investment Scheme." This program provides modest production and investment-linked subsidies and a phase down of its import tariff from 10 percent at the moment to 5 percent in 2010. The South African tariff is still 30 percent—a long way to go before encouraging competitiveness.
For more on this, including a link to the news story in question, see the Features page of my website.