09 April 2013
SA's Motor Industry—Once Again
The implicit answer, supported by a number of online reader comments, is that the industry is not internationally competitive. This is consistent with my own analysis over the years—the ability of MIDP and other government policies to attract investment and promote exports reflects, not the industry's competitiveness, but rather the value of government incentives.
The MIDP was recently replaced by the APDP. This tweaked some of the details of public support for the industry—production subsidies are now given to domestic sales as well as exports; the dti can now hand out cash investment incentives on a more discretionary basis. But the magnitude of public support has not diminished; and it is determined largely in consultation with the major firms who tell the government how much support they require to overcome the high costs of investing and producing in SA. In other words, the type and magnitude of public support depend on how uncompetitive these firms are in SA.
The danger now is that the dti will seek to solve this sectoral trade deficit "problem" in ways that will increase the burdens on consumers and taxpayers, and further diminish SA's manufacturing competitiveness. A simple "solution," for instance, would be to impose local content requirements on the industry and restrict imports through higher tariffs or other measures—in other words, return SA to the bizarre and highly costly policies of the Apartheid era.
The government could, and almost certainly will, employ more subtle subsidies and incentives to serve its motor industry clients. A tender document just released by the DPE, for instance, solicits advice on how Transnet and Eskom can be used to increase motor industry profitability. Reducing Transnet and Eskom costs would certainly be good for the entire economy. But to give special privileges to the motor industry (which already benefits from special Transnet pricing deals on its exports) would perpetuate the failures of the current policies that seek to improve competitiveness by subsidizing uncompetitive firms and industries.
25 March 2013
Subsidies, Bailouts and Markets
Of course, it is not just state companies and agencies that benefit from public subsidies. Direct government support and regulation are viewed by some as necessary for South African industrial development. The consequences of this approach can be similar to the effects of bailouts of state enterprises.
In this regard, Mr. Louw's remarks reminded me of a brilliant commentary by another FMF member, on the impacts of industrial policy in South Africa's motor industry. In a prize-winning letter to Business Day in 2005 Jim Harris explained how the MIDP (Motor Industry Development Program, recently rechristened as APDP) supports a few companies, but punishes consumers and retards the country's long-term economic development. His remarks were controversial and attracted fierce reactions from some fellow FMF members—at least those associated with the motor industry.
Mr. Harris' letter signalled the start of a vigorous public debate about MIDP that, if nothing else, clarified the nature and magnitude of the subsidies enjoyed by the industry. As with the bailouts of SAA, the MIDP and related subsidies protect a few heavily dependent companies at the expense of consumers, jobs and the poor.
I have been unable to find any follow-up on the FMF website to Jim Harris' early foray into South Africa's most important industrial policy. It would be useful for the FMF to complement the comments on bailouts to state enterprises (and on the US bailout of General Motors) with a discussion of the massive and continuing subsidies to firms in the South African motor industry and other selected sectors.
11 December 2009
Making a Mockery of Competitiveness
One of the few genuine innovations in South Africa's APDP, the motor industry support program that will replace the MIDP, is a requirement of a minimum scale of operations in order to qualify for the program's very generous financial benefits. Although the details of the program still have not been gazetted, we understand that in order to qualify vehicle assemblers will have to produce a minimum of 50,000 vehicles per year. The idea is to encourage international competitiveness by achieving some economies of scale in production.
The scheme does raise some questions.
1. Why is it necessary for the government to instruct global auto firms on efficient scales of production? (It is not; but under MIDP and APDP it is not necessary to be competitive in order to make big profits by producing in South Africa.)
2. Will production of 50,000 vehicles per year provide sufficient scale to compete with true international major league plants? (Generally not; competitive plants elsewhere produce at least 100,000 per year.)
3. And of course one might wonder how firms will try to get around the new requirement in order to continue to take advantage of the large subsidies made available by the government (and paid for through the "generosity" of South African vehicle consumers and taxpayers) without ramping up production.
But at least the new requirement appears to be a feint in the direction of encouraging some competitiveness on the part of the local industry.
An announcement by the government-operated East London Industrial Development Zone (ELIDZ) provides an answer to the third question. ELIDZ has told the press that it will soon announce the signing of several tenants in a new "multi-OEM assembly plant" it will build in the zone. What is the purpose of such a plant? To enable companies sharing the facility to produce at volumes of 10,000 vehicles per year, or even as low as just a few thousand and still qualify for the APDP benefits that are contingent on meeting the 50,000 per year volume target. It apparently will "work" as long as the total of all vehicles produced by all tenants reaches 50,000 per year.
How will this encourage increased competitiveness, the stated goal of the new policy? It will not. In fact it will simply replicate the highly inefficient pattern of small scale production of multiple models and other automotive products under one roof that was encouraged by protection in pre-MIDP days and by continued protection and MIDP benefits since then.
19 November 2008
A "New" Program of Auto Industry Support
17 July 2007
Unsafe at any Speed: MIDP and SACU
The articles cleverly explore the links between SACU's new revenue sharing formula, South Africa's Motor Industry Development Program (MIDP) and the recent boom in car sales in South Africa, to illustrate how the new formula turns all previous interests in SACU trade policy on their heads. By fattening the government budgets of the four small and less developed SACU members (Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia and Swaziland—the "BLNS countries" in SACU-speak) the formula has turned these countries into avid supporters of a program designed to subsidize South African motor industry producers at the expense of South African and BLNS consumers. The cost of the program to BLNS consumers is now dwarfed by the (far more than) offsetting revenue transfers to BLNS governments (to the tune of 23 percent of GDP in the case of Lesotho and 12 percent in Swaziland). And now poor South African consumers/taxpayers are saddled not only with high priced motor vehicles but also with the burden of huge fiscal transfers to the BLNS.
South Africa's National Treasury, quite naturally, is bemoaning not only the size of the revenue transfers, but also the difficulties they will create in reaching agreement on badly needed rationalization of the SACU tariff structure. Under the new SACU arrangement, tariff rate decisions are meant to be decided collectively by all members. Having been turned into the greatest supporters of South Africa's protectionist trade policies, the BLNS countries are unlikely to favour tariff reductions that threaten their fiscal windfalls. Before complaining too much, however, South Africa should look at its own central role in promoting agreement on this new revenue formula.
Among the cutest parts of the M&G articles is an illustrative calculation of the amount of revenues transferred to the BLNS whenever a South African buys a new imported car. Based on an import duty rate of 25 percent and an assumed transfer of about half of these revenues to the BLNS, the article shows that the purchaser of a new "Volvaru" that cost a dealer R200 000 would pay just over R25 000 to the BLNS, of which about R5 000 would go to the government of Swaziland and R4 100 to Lesotho.
In fact the numbers are much worse than that. The import duty on cars is now 30 percent, not 25 percent. And, according to our estimates of last year, the share of duty collections going to the BLNS is about 88 percent, not 50 percent. This means that a South African buyer of the above-mentioned "Volvaru" would contribute about R52 000 to the BLNS, of which over R11 000 would go to Swaziland and R7 400 to Lesotho (and greater amounts to the governments of Botswana and Namibia).
This tale leaves South African consumers and taxpayers with much to ponder. The consequences of the MIDP and of the new SACU arrangement are surely much different than whatever might have been expected by those who designed them; and their combined impact is far worse than either of them individually. Two bad policies do not make a good one.
09 May 2007
South Africa's MIDP
However, an industry representative was reported yesterday as saying that government support of the industry is "below par" relative to other countries and will have to be improved in order to make the industry competitive.
How much support has the MIDP given the industry? Answers to this basic question are difficult to obtain. I have estimated that typical subsidies to motor vehicle and/or components manufacturers range from 260 to over 650 percent of the size of MIDP-supported investments.
Support to the motor industry from export subsidies and import duties has almost certainly exceeded R100 billion over the life of the program so far. The cost to consumers has been similar. How can an industry that relies on such levels of support expect to become "competitive"? Surely the solution is not to give even more subsidies.
Australia, after whose program the MIDP was initially modelled, is entering the final phase of its "Automotive Competitivness and Investment Scheme." This program provides modest production and investment-linked subsidies and a phase down of its import tariff from 10 percent at the moment to 5 percent in 2010. The South African tariff is still 30 percent—a long way to go before encouraging competitiveness.
For more on this, including a link to the news story in question, see the Features page of my website.